CAIRN.INFO : Matières à réflexion

1Transportation is the cornerstone of almost every modern economic activity, rendering possible the function of the market economy [1]. In the course of the 19th century, railways played a decisive role within the transportation system. However, in most modern economies, railways passed their central position to the motor carrier during the second half of the 20th century. Despite that trend, Switzerland preserved a dense railway network (Figure 1) and nowadays the railways still maintain a considerable market share, even in rural areas. While economists more and more intensively claimed that the mode of transportation was secondary and that in a service economy transport costs were about to become less important to the economic development [2], politicians clung to the belief of indispensable railways and protected them from the menace of the free market.

2In Switzerland, the interpretation of the country’s own history as a « special case », different from and not comparable to other nations, is almost a traditional way of thought. All too often, the theory of a Swiss special case is considered to be a sufficient explanation for the unusual phenomenon in question. Certainly, this is the case in Swiss transportation history. The virtually mystified history of Swiss railways has thus far been written by biased engineers rather than academically trained historians and has rarely gone beyond straight forward explanations of the causes of varying historic developments, including the heroic tunnelling of the Alps in the 19th century, the fast and nationalistically connoted electrification during the first half of the 20th century [3], or the extraordinary density of the Swiss railway network right up to the present. This is a rather amazing fact in view of the importance of transportation services to the economy. The assumed « special case » of Switzerland’s transportation history is of scientific interest. We think that Swiss railway history should be rewritten as part of a political history of a still very important part of the economy.

3In the first part of this paper, we provide a short outline of the organisational pattern of the Swiss railway system and of the economic decline of the so-called « private » railway companies after World War II. TrainBase is an appropriate working tool for that purpose because it is a database which includes the digitalized railway history of Switzerland from 1920 through 1982. It is therefore possible to compare the different accounts of all suppliers of railbound-transportation service in Switzerland [4]. In the second part, we illustrate the countermeasures of the Swiss state against the economic malaise of the private railway industry. And finally, we outline some of the underlying causes and justifications of the policies depicted.

The Swiss railway system in the 20th century

Organisational pattern

4In Switzerland, one of the most eye-catching characteristics of the railway industry is its twofold structure, including the state-owned Swiss Federal Railways (SBB) and a rather fragmented « private » sector consisting of some 60 varying stock companies, mainly – but not exclusively – owned by the cantons. Originally, all the railways were constituted as private companies, but the cantons and municipalities signed major parts of the initial capital in order to foster the local economic development. But in 1897, the Swiss voted for the nationalization of the five most important railway companies, thereby founding the Swiss Federal Railways SBB. As of 1902, the SBB operated about 3000km of tracks, while the remaining 2000km were still served by the so-called « private » companies. By then, the main lines of the railway network, which had generally been completed by the end of the 19th century, was in the hands of the Swiss central state. However, through the support of the cantons and municipalities, a number of small companies were established at the beginning of the 20th century in order to connect the alpine valleys and small towns with the main network. As in other countries, railway construction was part of the regional economic policies, but the federal government did not participate in bearing the costs of the new, rarely profitable railway companies. In accordance with Switzerland’s strong conviction of the principles of subsidiarity and federalism, the national administration was solely accountable for the SBB, leaving the by-lines of the railway system in the hands of lower levels of government. Thus, Switzerland’s private (or cantonal) railways basically operated the by-lines of the network – far from the big flow of goods and passengers – and connected the economically often underprivileged and peripheral alpine regions with the more prosperous regions of the central plateau. The foundation of the SBB brought about two, legally differing railway sectors showing various organisational patterns and started off from very unequal economic premises. Unlike in Britain, France and Germany, the nationalization of Swiss railways remained incomplete.

Figure 1

Length of railway networks in Europe, 1900–1990 Source: Mitchell B.R. et al., 2003, International Historical Statistics : Europe 1750-2000, (vol. 2), New York, pp. 674-683

Figure 1

Length of railway networks in Europe, 1900–1990 Source: Mitchell B.R. et al., 2003, International Historical Statistics : Europe 1750-2000, (vol. 2), New York, pp. 674-683

Figure 2

Labour and capital productivity of the Swiss private and federal railways, 1945-1982

Figure 2

Labour and capital productivity of the Swiss private and federal railways, 1945-1982

Source: TrainBase

5As a consequence of the emergence of the motor carrier as a strong competitor on the transportation market following World War II, the railway networks in many European nations were gradually shortened to their trunk lines (Figure 1). In Switzerland, however, where the spur lines were exploited by the private railway sector, the network amazingly persisted as a whole, even though private railway companies faced severe financial difficulties, as did most European railways. The question remains as to just how the private railway industry managed to survive.

Small, unproductive and in economic troubles : Switzerland’s private railway companies

6Because the five corporations unified as the SBB represented the main axes of the Swiss railway network, it is not astonishing that the importance of the state railways for the entire transportation sector was incomparably higher than that of the private sector. From 1920 to 1980, the gap between the two sectors even deepened. While the SBB by 1980 had achieved an increase of their transport output to the fivefold amount of 1920, the private sector only managed to triple their services. Relative to the motor carrier and compared to the SBB, the private railways lost a disproportionate share of the transportation market.

7In its structure, the private sector presented itself extraordinarily fragmented. In 1920, an archetypal railway company operated only 22km of tracks. Due to a number of closures and mergers, which reduced the number of corporations in operation from 80 (1920) to 58 as of 1982, the average track length increased to 33km. In the 1950s, an average private railway company employed about 100 people and operated with 3 locomotives, 6 railcars and 18 carriages. Such companies, therefore, can be characterized as mere small-scale enterprises on the transportation market.

8However, neither the loss of relative market shares nor the fragmented structure of the private sector must necessarily mean that the private railway companies had to be less profitable than the larger state railways. It is evident that not the dimension of a company but their productivity decides over profit or loss. But, as Figure 2 shows, both labour and capital productivity of the private companies were inferior to those of the SBB and their increase of productivity in the second half of the 20th century was noticeably slower. Thus, until the beginning of the 1970s, the SBB managed to compensate the downward tendency of transportation prices by a sufficient enhancement of overall productivity, meanwhile being one of the most profitable railway undertakings in Europe, presenting balanced books of payment until the economic slowdown after the first « oil-crisis » in 1973 [5]. At the same time, the private railway sector as a whole indicated continual operating losses as transportation earnings and costs started to drift apart (Figure 3).

9The financial failure of the private sector had its consequences, but that did result in the closing of railway routes. Instead, Swiss Parliament forced the federal treasury to help the cantons concerned in balancing the books of those railways with highly devaluated capital (« Privatbahnhilfegesetz » / «Sanierungshilfen ») [6]. As a result of those financial amendments by the cantons and the confederation, private capital came to be more lastingly withdrawn from the railway industry and was substituted by public funds. For fully private corporations, bankruptcy would have been the logical consequence of the financial performance of Swiss private railway companies as demonstrated so far. Without a doubt, Switzerland suspended the functions of the free market in favour of the rail-bound transportation industry. But how and, above all, why did the Swiss save a good part of their economically obsolete railroad system ?

Figure 3

Costs and earnings per transport unit (t-km/personkm) SBB and private railways, 1945-1982

Figure 3

Costs and earnings per transport unit (t-km/personkm) SBB and private railways, 1945-1982

Source : TrainBase.

Political reactions to the financial constraints

Public funds from World War I to the 1970s

10After a prolonged period of increased operating revenues, the Swiss railway industry again experienced low profitability when World War I broke out. On the eve of the war, most companies operated at a loss and would have filed for bankruptcy if even the mere thought of economic effectiveness and success had been prevalent [7]. But instead of taking into consideration the closure of at least a part of the whole network, a vast majority of the contemporary policy makers upheld the conviction that railways were an indispensable element of the national transport system. As a consequence, Parliament decided to intervene and conceived a concept of financial aid which has been applied since then [8]. After years of having been reluctant to grant public funds in favour of the continuation of the enterprises, albeit not in dispensing subsidies for their initial construction, the Swiss government renounced its former principles and provided generous funding, even for daily business operations. Finally, the first federal decree in aid of the afflicted companies was enacted by the Federal Assembly on December 18th, 1918, a step foreshadowing more ambitious initiatives in the following years and proving to be a real break through in the regulatory regime in Swiss railway policy [9].

11After this turning point, which obviously has to be seen in the context of wartime economy, three types of grants came to be established within the next forty years. Firstly, the legislature framed a so-called emergency aid for the maintenance of business (« Krisenhilfe zur Aufrechterhaltung des Betriebes »), covering the operative losses in order to prevent short-term cases of insolvency. As a result, companies confronted with failure were offered the chance to request governmental assistance as soon as the total amount of their operating expenses exceeded the revenues. However, due to the fear of benefits to private stockholders, it was not allowed to pay interest, return loans or distribute dividends at the expense of the state [10]. Secondly, due to these aforementioned restricting conditions and given the fact that most of the originally private companies were in the meantime state-owned, two Redevelopment Acts (« Sanierungshilfen ») were passed [11]. They met the demands for a consolidation of the balance sheets on which the equity ratio appeared too low and both the credit capital and the invested capital were too high. Indeed, such liabilities and overvalued assets eliminated any possibility to roll over or repay the obtained credits or even to attract investment capital for required improvements. Furthermore, for public redevelopments, the companies weighted down by debts would not have been financially viable in the long run [12]. Thirdly, as a further reaction to such paralytic symptoms on part of the companies, the state became engaged in technical modernisation, and the outcome was a first investment assistance (« Investitionshilfe »), the Electrification Act of 1919. Passed at a time when public interest in a fully functional transportation system was threatened by the post-war economic crisis and especially by a rise in the price of coal, this type of railway legislation rendered it possible to change the traction system towards domestic electricity [13].

12Nonetheless, in spite of this wide range of public funding, the underlying basic law on railways dating back to December 20th, 1872, neither foresaw state activities like these nor provided any further specifications about them. Therefore, whenever new financial measures were planned, Parliament – both the National Council and the Council of States – had to approve them each individual time by a specific act [14]. As a result, the rhythm of the subsidies granted did not follow a regular pattern but accelerated with the outbreak of extraordinary events, such as the Great Depression starting in 1929 or World War II a decade later. It therefore became mandatory to deal with the problem of an ailing rail industry. Nevertheless, the more the required sums were increased (Table 1), the more there was an urgent need for a sufficient basic law which would enable the granting of financial aid in greater amounts and, above all, at regular intervals [15].

Figure 4
Table 1: Public funds for railways, 1918 – 1957 (in million nominal Swiss Francs) Year emergency aid investment assistance redevelopment 1918 1 1919 32.8 1933 0.9 1939 140 1940 0.6 1951 3 1957 9 Total amount 14.5 32.8 140 Source: Hans Reinhard Meyer/Alfred Hess, Die staatliche Hilfeleistung, in: Eidg. Amt für Verkehr (Hg.), Ein Jahrhundert Schweizer Bahnen 1847 – 1947 (Bd. 1), Frauenfeld 1947, pp. 430 – 432; BBl 1957/I, p. 933.

13Hence, for the sake of a standardised form of subsidisation, all important trade associations, various labour unions, all political parties and the railways themselves pushed for a new, all-embracing law that would offer financial security to the railway system as a whole. Even in the early 1940s, they still hoped for a sudden increase of rail passengers and freight transportation, and they tenaciously refused any change in railway policy. Track shortages, mergers, or conversion to bus services were discussed but strictly refused, even by politicians who were generally in favour of a free market and extremely disinclined to regulatory measures. Therefore, following a perennial period of negotiations which were delayed by other ongoing law projects, the long-desired, renewed federal statute providing guidelines for the Swiss railways was passed on December 23rd, 1957 [16].

14Under the title of « Financial Aid », chapter VII of this act specifically perpetuated the existing public grants and offered the possibility – but did not impose an obligation (!) – of supporting all railway companies with regular financial contributions. Firstly, this involved the well-known emergency aid for the maintenance of business that was codified in article 58. Once again, the aim was to prevent the companies from collapsing, but now with the decisive difference that the depreciation and amortisation of fixed capital was counted as part of the operating expenses. As a result, the available funds as well as those paid remained on a continual increase for the next several years, especially as of 1972, when article 58 was integrated into the ordinary federal budget [17]. Secondly, the previous Redevelopment Acts and the investment assistance were merged into article 56, which thereby enabled companies to benefit from allowances for the technical improvement of their infrastructure [18]. Thirdly, as an amendment reflecting the predominant emergence of new modes of transportation, article 57 allowed the state to encourage the transformation of a company into a bus service through the aid of public funds. At first glance, it appeared that for the first time ever the state was signalling a renunciation of the heretofore existing insistence on an area-wide railway system. However, over the course of the next decades, this new trend proved to be a sheer dissimulation because in many cases neither the companies nor the policy makers invoked this article [19].

15In addition, the National Assembly extended the range of financial aid by creating a completely new form of public funds. Whereas the traditional ways had formed a pure ex post reaction to the malaise, the legislature now intended that enterprises could be prevented from getting into trouble. For this purpose, sector VI was inserted in the renewed Railway Act by the two Councils against the declared will of the government and the federal administration. It was reflected in article 51 on the premise that the railways should be paid compensation for the services they rendered to the general economy. Completely unlike the previous financial aid, this type of public allowances was not considered to be a subsidisation but a real indemnification (« Abgeltung ») of the so-called fundamental obligations (« gemeinwirtschaftliche Pflichten ») under which the companies had been since the time of the monopoly. In other words, most of the contemporary politicians, economists, and the companies themselves took the position that the railways, on the one hand, were rightly entitled to such a contribution and, on the other hand, that this would diminish the « real » public grants to a minimum [20].

16Instead, however, of the hoped-for heavy decrease and to the bitter disappointment of the actors involved, the federal expenditures for railway services and infrastructure actually skyrocketed within the next fifteen years (Figure 4). Even in the National Assembly, where the representatives of the remote regions of Switzerland had enforced the financial aid against the will of the administration, a certain scepticism arose and some very dissenting voices were soon heard. Nevertheless, the primary measures that had been taken against the financial constraints of the railways in Switzerland consisted in public funding for the benefit of all cash-strapped companies since 1918. As pointed out earlier however, in spite of this remarkable generosity, which lasted at least until the late 1970s, the Swiss state and the policy system did not succeed in bailing the companies out of their financial difficulties, as was also the case in other European countries.

Figure 4

Public funds for private railways, 1958 – 1972 (million nominal Swiss Francs)Source: Verkehrsstatistik 1974, S. 234 – 236; BBl 1970/II, S. 344

Figure 4

Public funds for private railways, 1958 – 1972 (million nominal Swiss Francs)Source: Verkehrsstatistik 1974, S. 234 – 236; BBl 1970/II, S. 344

Railway policy in the name of public utilities

17As a consequence of the rising subsidisation, the railway system as a whole increasingly came under suspicion of being sluggish, profligate and inefficient. Seen from this point of view, most of the companies aspired to obtain as much public funds as they could, whereas they failed to achieve increased earnings or at least to improve their performance [21]. Furthermore, referring to the ongoing deterioration of railways, the critics blamed the regulatory apparatus of the state both for stifling any innovation and for hampering intermodal competition. The critics claimed that the situation could not improve unless the financial aid, which they regarded as the very reason for the weakening rail economy, were to be stopped or at least reduced. Accordingly, signalling a fundamental change in policy, they urged an end to state control over the rail industry and asserted that a greater reliance on the market would be essential in order to achieve maximum utilisation of railways [22].

18To be sure, the clamour for restoring competition and, as a consequence, for privately operated railways was hardly audible in the 1960s and the 1970s. Although state authority had not been able to change the situation until then, only a few academic studies – influenced by the German transport economists who first called for deregulation and going-private of any transportation system – blamed railway regulation as neither benefiting carriers nor consumers. Amongst Swiss economists, Hans Reinhard Meyer (1910 – 2005), an associate professor at the University of Bern, was for a long time the only one who called for a reduction of governmental control and constantly pointed to a waste of public funds [23]. At the beginning of the 1990s, most of his colleagues, some progressive politicians and the liberal-minded media were disenchanted with the federal administration of the carriers. Regardless of whether they were aware of their predecessor or not, they resumed Meyer’s discussion and questioned the wisdom of public financial assistance to the railways, renewing the request for privatisation and embracing open markets. At the same time, railroads definitively gained the reputation of lacking entrepreneurial spirit, and again, the most common allegation made was that they were an idle beneficiary of the state wasting its money [24].

19However, considering the antagonism between exploding public grants and the scepticism which such a development provoked in the field of economic research, a critical history of transportation has to pose the question as to why Swiss policy makers were always reluctant to minimize the financial aid and, accordingly, why they still are. Furthermore, it is also worthwhile to analyse which business strategy the companies have adopted over the years : did they really behave so indolently and rely on the state as they were blamed ?

20As to the first problem, it is important to bear in mind its roots in the 19th century. The first railway lines were typically financed by local investors with the aid of state and local governments for the purpose of increasing commerce. Consequently, investors and government officials had a proprietary expectation that « their » company would primarily serve local interests [25]. This was mainly due to their conviction that railways would stimulate both the economy and the growth of the population all over the country – especially in remote areas – by keeping freight rates low. Transportation costs had been prohibitively high up to that time, this being caused by an energy input that was necessarily enormous. With the new railways it became possible for the first time to haul goods over long distances by land carriers [26]. Under these conditions, as local manufacturing was gradually replaced with worldwide market integration and international division of labour, it was only a short step to treat private railway companies as an instrument of commercial policy. Anxious to guarantee that not only the growing cities and the centrally located areas gained an advantage by rail transportation, the state soon decided to adopt a command-and-control approach towards the whole business [27]. The railway companies therefore became more and more saddled with a rigid regulatory regime that mainly consisted of the above-mentioned fundamental obligations. That meant that they were legally bound to carry each piece of freight and each passenger at any time and everywhere at equally low rates. Basically, the enterprises were not permitted to repudiate any of their potentially interested customers. Reflecting the strong conviction that railways touched the economic life of most people, this was targeted on ensuring an absolute equality in the conditions of transportation. No one should be discriminated, particularly because rail traffic had a virtual monopoly at the close of the 19th century [28].

21Fifty years later, in the interwar period and far beyond, the same attitude towards rail industry and its obligations had not changed, notwithstanding the first critical remarks in scholarly pieces dating from the late 1960s. Along with the promise of economic growth, railways still played a key role in the contemporary concept of transportation. Yet, with a renewed emphasis on their function of being promoters of the economic development, the railways were regarded as a public work, established by public authority and intended for public use and benefit, the use of which was secured to the entire community. Even the rise of the motor carrier as a strong competitor and the radical modification it caused on the market failed to prevent this opinion from being echoed by all political parties as well as by the media and, above all, by trade associations. Precisely these facts were the reason why the liquidation of any company was deemed totally unacceptable, even though the maintenance and modernisation of such enterprises gobbled up more and more public grants. Moreover, despite the obvious decline of most of the companies and the falling off of railway traffic, the legislature did not feel compelled to justify the financial aid in a detailed way. In fact, during the period between 1918 and the early 1970s, it became customary and absolutely sufficient to bring forward the argument of the railway that occupied – thanks to its fundamental obligations – a central place in the economic life of the entire country [29].

22However, in the late 1960s the general consensus on this issue began to crumble. Pursuing a new policy that shifted the emphasis slightly away from the hitherto accepted paradigms, some members of Parliament began referring to the public demand for protecting the environment, a matter which took on increased importance at that time. Under the impression that the accelerated economic growth and its by-products harmed nature and life and that it would be impossible to prolong it endlessly, politicians called for a change of course, especially in traffic affairs. The railways, which thus far had been continuingly squeezed out of the market by cars, turned out to be a panacea for finding the way out of the dilemma which maintained that freight and passenger transportation were absolutely indispensable on the one hand, but allegedly polluted the environment on the other [30]. From this perspective, the needs of both the economy and ecology could only be satisfied at once if at least the long-distance haulage was carried by rail while automobiles primarily served as a short-distance linkage. Therefore, the National Assembly insisted on their well-known strategy, according to which every railway company had to be prevented from falling into ruin, and they remained opposed to any idea of reducing the existing level of subsidy [31]. The public utilities which had justified the rising financial support and the state involvement up to that time no longer meant that the economic wealth throughout the country was fostered by railway transportation but rather assumed that the railway companies made a contribution to environmental protection. Thus, the late 1970s proved to be a real turning point regarding the argumentation in favour of the railways in Switzerland and their public grants [32].

23Nevertheless, with reference to the allegations made first by Meyer and with time by the vast majority of economists, the question arises whether the asserted bottleneck as well as the complete standstill of the railway companies should be revised in light of historical research. However, given the fact that the railway policy in the course of the 20th century shows conspicuous gaps in historiography, filling such an enormous space is obviously beyond the scope of this paper. Therefore, the problem can best be illustrated with the activities of the enterprises in view of their tariff structure during the 1940s and 1950s. For this purpose, the key to establishing such an understanding is to know that every change of freight and passenger rates, whether a reduction or a rise, required regulatory approval in the first place. Unlike the truck drivers who could bargain directly with shippers and passengers over scales, railways had lost that privilege and were not allowed any tariff reforms before they had worked their way through a system of public supervision. Furthermore, apart from this time-consuming procedure which lasted several months on the average, most of the national trade and industrial associations, such as the Swiss Farmers’ Union and the representative bodies of the coal, wood-working, or export-oriented industries, were given a say in all decisions on rates. That meant that whenever the companies planned to make any even minor adjustments, their plans first had to be discussed in the so-called Commercial Conference [33].

24A short glance at the very first all-out tariff reform, which took place from 1946 to 1952, reveals that this programme was originally initiated by the railways themselves. Once they realised that in the post-war period their legally founded rate structure did not meet their needs in the hard-fought transportation market, they wanted to revolutionize it. Above all, their efforts focused on adjusting all taxes to their real cost structure. Whereas lower charges for agricultural products had been made up for thus far by higher rates on other goods, this company-internal burden sharing had to be stopped as soon as possible. Pointing out the losses which they constantly had to bear, the companies attributed the necessary modifications to the fact that their inflated rates on high-priced goods had frequently been undercut by motor carriers in a kind of cream-skimming strategy. But as ambitious as they were, it was a dead duck in attempting to persuade their negotiating partners to accept their new tariff scheme. Both economic representatives as well as the deputies of the cantons refused to abandon the traditional rate system. Inasmuch as the policy makers were convinced that favourable rates should be fixed to assist ailing segments of the economy, the more lucrative freights should still contribute to the unprofitable charges without any restrictions. For instance, the Grisons Cantonal Council stressed the argument that public utilities would be predominant also in questions concerning transportation rates : « We feel strongly confident that the general interest of a country has to prevail over the profitable efficiency of the railway enterprises in any case » [34]. And likewise, Ernst Jaggi (1917 – 2004), director of the Swiss Farmer’s Union at that time, denied any claims by the companies to be operating at a profit : « It is not allowed to pursue a railway policy only on principles of profitability » [35]. In the end, such objections were taken into account by the Federal Council in their capacity as supreme authority upon being coerced to make a decision about the tariff issues due to the dissension within the Commercial Conference. In 1952, the rate structure of the railways showed the same peculiarities as previously and as it would continue to do until the late 1970s because of the failure of several ensuing reform projects. Therefore, most of the remote areas in the country as well as some of the industrial sectors – and above all, agriculture, which relied on the axiom of public utilities – seemed to be the only ones to profit from the Swiss railways policy. They all prevented the rail industry from working more efficiently, whereas the cost-conscious companies strove for increasing revenues and a higher profitability. As is evident, the scathing attack on the performance and management of the railways, primarily launched by Meyer and his successors, must be reconsidered and put into historical perspective at least for the period between 1945 and 1975 [36].

Conclusion

25In the period under review, the Swiss rail industry has been structurally split into two sectors, featuring the SBB as a state-run enterprise as well as a private sector of around 60 stock companies that were, in fact more often than not, owned by the cantons. The SBB, an amalgamation of the five most important private companies founded in the 19th century, operated the most profitable axes of the Swiss railway network. Due to their economies of scale, they managed at least to break even until the 1970s, whereas the private companies experienced a much lower productivity. Therefore, when answering the question as to why the Swiss did not dismantle their railway network as did most of the other European nations, one has to focus on the private sector, which always represented the real candidates for track shortages.

26Being aware of the financial difficulties of the private railways, the Swiss policymakers constructed an elaborate safety net that granted operating losses, fostered investment for the improvement of the capital stock of the railways and financially compensated the railways services in favour of the general interest. This system, which had its roots in the Railway Act of 1957, has remained partially intact right up to the present, having undergone some conceptual changes during the Railway Reform in 1996. The National Assembly repeatedly justified this policy with the positive externalities which railways were supposed to have on the economy, especially in remote areas and, somewhat later, on environmental issues. On a lower level of government, clearly definable interests of local pressure groups such as the farmer’s union or tourism, as well as trade unions, were of great importance, particularly when bargaining over tariff rates made in the Commercial Conference or within the democratic structures of the cantons. Deploying the argument of economical and environmental impacts the railway allegedly should have, they in fact primarily served their own interests. Switzerland’s political system and the special organizational structure of its railway system allowed local interest groups to actively participate in the shaping of national railway policy and thereby avoid the reduction of the network.

Notes

  • [1]
    Cf. Voigt, 1973, p. 9.
  • [2]
    Meyer, 1976, pp. 18 – 21 ; Meyer, 1966, pp. 285 – 304.
  • [3]
    Merki 1995, pp. 444 – 457.
  • [4]
    Visit our database online : www. trainbase. ch.
  • [5]
    Cf. Müller, 1981.
  • [6]
    BBL 1939/I, pp. 579 – 583.
  • [7]
    BBl 1918/IV, pp. 504 – 513 ; BBl 1916/III, pp. 441 – 443.
  • [8]
    For a first comprehensive survey of the financial history of the Swiss railways, cf. Kirchhofer, 2003.
  • [9]
    BBl 1956/I, p. 217 ; Kunz 1955, p. 673.
  • [10]
    BBl 1918/IV, pp. 504 – 521 ; StenBull NR 1918, pp. 554 – 576 ; StenBull SR 1918, pp. 159 – 192.
  • [11]
    BBL 1939/I, pp. 579 – 583.
  • [12]
    BBl 1937/I, pp. 741 – 815 ; StenBull NR 1939, p. 346 ; StenBull SR 1939, pp. 342 – 344.
  • [13]
    BBl 1919/II, pp. 142 – 153 ; StenBull NR 1919, pp. 745 – 757 ; StenBull SR 1919, pp. 259 – 274, 525–526. For the development of the public grants during the interwar years, cf. Kirchhofer, 2003, pp. 111 – 125.
  • [14]
    BBl 1956/II, pp. 253 – 256 ; BBl 1954/I, pp. 1013 – 1015 ; BBl 1951/I, pp. 885 – 890 ; BBl 1940/I, pp. 1249 – 1250 ; BBl 1937/II, pp. 429 – 436 ; BBl 1933/I, pp. 344 – 357.
  • [15]
    cf. Kirchhofer, 2003, pp. 117 – 118.
  • [16]
    BBl 1956/I, pp. 213 – 315 ; Sten Bull SR 1957, pp. 127 – 205 ; Sten Bull NR 1957, pp. 693 – 765, 1050 ; cf. Kirchhofer, 2003, pp. 125 – 141.
  • [17]
    Kieliger, 1981, pp. 53 – 57 ; Anderegg, 1978, p. 34.
  • [18]
    Kieliger, 1981, pp. 45 – 53.
  • [19]
    Kieliger, 1981, pp. 57 – 58.
  • [20]
    Kieliger, 1981, pp. 24 – 44 ; Anderegg, 1978, pp. 26 – 27, 32 ; Kirchhofer, 2003, pp. 142 – 154.
  • [21]
    Cf. Stamm, 1979 ; Roth, 1978 ; Meyer, 1976.
  • [22]
    Ruchti, 1973, pp. 127 – 146.
  • [23]
    Meyer, 1976, pp. 94 – 99. The Swiss and the German school of transport economics and their changes in thinking about public funds are described in a more detailed way in Kirchhofer, 2007.
  • [24]
    Cf. Bättig, 2003 ; Frey, 2000, pp. 92 – 99 ; European Conference of Ministers of Transport, 1993 ; Willeke, 2001, pp. 52 – 72 ; Willeke, 1997, pp. 52 – 72 ; Blöchliger, 1993 ; Knieps, 1993, pp. 249 – 259 ; Weibel, 1993 ; Brändli, 1992, pp. 515 – 517 ; Kaspar, 1990.
  • [25]
    Pfister, 1995, p. 259.
  • [26]
    Cf. Frey, Vogel, 1993 ; Rüfenacht, Salis Gross, 1993.
  • [27]
    Cf. Sax, 1878.
  • [28]
    Cf. Bauer, 1947, pp. 3-180 ; Spörri, 1941 ; Saitzew, 1932.
  • [29]
    Kirchhofer, 2007, pp. 228-234.
  • [30]
    Walter, 1996, pp. 174-188 ; Skenderovic, 1994, pp. 33-61.
  • [31]
    StenBull NR, 1971, pp. 180-189 ; BBl, 1975/II, pp. 1449-1474 ; BBl, 1981/II, pp. 1392-1421.
  • [32]
    Treichler, 1996, p. 191 ; Kirchhofer, 2007, pp. 203-213, 328-340.
  • [33]
    Cf. Kommerzieller Dienst Personenverkehr, 1973.
  • [34]
    Kleiner Rat Kanton Graubünden, Schreiben vom 15. Dezember 1951, p. 4 (BAR 8100 (B), 1973/154, Bd. 92)
  • [35]
    EPED, Protokoll vom 22. Dezember 1951, p. 5 (BAR 8100 (B), 1973/154, Bd. 92).
  • [36]
    Kirchhofer, 2006, pp. 57-66.
English

Abstract

In the course of the 20th century the Swiss railway industry, which has to be considered an anomaly because of its division into a state sector and a so-called « private » one, got into financial difficulties, as did the railways in other countries. Almost all enterprises constantly operated at a loss and experienced low profitability as soon as they were deprived of their hitherto existing transportation monopoly by the upcoming motor carrier. But unlike other European countries, Switzerland has so far renounced to dismantle its railway system to a large extent. Even in the remote areas where freight and passenger traffic has become less profitable – and often very much so – over the decades, the network is still maintained in these days as it was built up in the 19th and the early 20th century.
Given the fact that fully private incorporations would have filed for bankruptcy on the same conditions, the paper focuses on the question of how Swiss railway policy dealt with the financial constraints of the private rail industry and, above all, why it did so. In answer to that, it has to be pointed out that the state constantly provided generous funding, which was due to the strong conviction that railway companies were absolutely indispensable to the equilibrated economic development of the whole national economy including the mountainous regions. On the other hand, the companies themselves did not always rely on these public grants (for which they were blamed by some scholars of economics), but tried for example to reform their tariff systems – with the disappointing result that they were deterred from doing so by some trade associations.

Français

Résumé

Au cours du XXe siècle, les chemins de fer suisses, qui étaient considérés comme une anomalie puisque constitués d’un secteur étatique et d’un secteur soi-disant « privé », rencontrèrent des difficultés financières, comme les chemins de fer d’autres pays. La plupart des entreprises exploitèrent à perte et connurent une faible rentabilité dès qu’elles furent privées de leur position de monopole avec la montée en puissance des transports routiers. Mais contrairement aux autres pays européens, la Suisse a renoncé à démanteler son système ferroviaire, et ce, à grande échelle. Même dans les zones éloignées où le trafic de marchandises et de voyageurs est devenu moins rentable — et souvent, très peu rentable — durant des décennies, le réseau est resté le même que celui qui avait été construit au XIXe et au début du XXe siècle.
Considérant que des entreprises privées auraient couru à la faillite dans de telles conditions, l’article cherche à comprendre comme la politique ferroviaire suisse s’est accommodée des contraintes du privé, et surtout, pourquoi elle l’a fait. Pour y répondre, il faut mettre en avant le fait que l’État a constamment et généreusement subventionné le secteur ferroviaire, ce qui était dû à la conviction forte que les compagnies de chemin de fer étaient absolument indispensables au développement économique équilibré du pays dans son ensemble, c’est-à-dire y compris les régions montagneuses. D’autre part, les compagnies elles-mêmes ne comptèrent pas sur ces subventions publiques (à propos desquelles certains économistes les condamnaient), mais essayèrent par exemple de réformer leurs systèmes tarifaires – dans un contexte décevant où elles en furent dissuadées par certaines associations commerciales.

REFERENCES

  • Scholarly literature

    • Anderegg F., 1978, Schweizerische und Bernische Eisenbahn-Gesetzgebung und Hilfeleistung vom Jahre 1852 bis zur Gegenwart, Bern.
    • Bättig M., 2003, Zukünftige Kooperationsformen bei schweizerischen Eisenbahnunternehmungen im Umfeld von Deregulierung, Privatisierung und Bahnreform : Ein Systemansatz (Diplomarbeit phil. nat. Universität Bern), Bern.
    • Bauer H. 1947, « Die Geschichte der schweizerischen Eisenbahnen », in Eidgenössisches Amt für Verkehr (ed.), Ein Jahrhundert Schweizer Bahnen 1847 – 1947 (vol. 1), Frauenfeld, pp. 3-180.
    • Blöchliger U., 1993, Deregulierung und Restrukturierung im schweizerischen Eisenbahnwesen (Doppelsemesterarbeit rer. pol. Universität Zürich), Zürich.
    • Brändli H., 1992, « Privatisierung, Harmonisierung, Regionalisierung, Deregulierung. Schlagworte auf dem Weg zu einem besseren öffentlichen Verkehr ? », Schweizer Eisenbahn-Revue 11, pp. 515-517.
    • European Conference of Ministers of Transport, 1993, Privatisation of railways (Report of the 9th Round Table on Transport Economics, 4th – 5th February 1993, Paris), Paris.
    • Frey T., Vogel L., 1993, « Und wenn wir auch die Eisenbahn mit Kälte begrüssen…», Verkehrsintensivierung in der Schweiz 1870 – 1910: Ihre Auswirkungen auf Demographie, Wirtschaft und Raumstruktur (Diss. phil. hist. Universität Zürich), Zürich.
    • Frey W., 2000, « Unter bestimmten Rahmenbedingungen reguliert der Markt am besten », in : Blindenbacher R., Hablützel P., Letsch B. (eds.), Vom Service Public zum Service au Public. Regierung und Verwaltung auf dem Weg in die Zukunft, Zürich, pp. 92-99.
    • Kaspar C., 1990, Herausforderungen der Liberalisierung des EG-Binnenmarktes für die Schweizer Verkehrspolitik, St. Gallen.
    • Kieliger K., 1981, Die Subventionen an die schweizerischen Privatbahnen. Eine Erfolgskontrolle (Diss. iur. Universität Zürich), Bern.
    • Kirchhofer A., 2007, Stets zu Diensten – gezwungenermassen ! Die Schweizer Bahnen und ihre « Gemeinwirtschaftlichkeit » für Staat, Wirtschaft und Bevölkerung (Diss. phil. hist. Universität Bern), Bern.
    • Kirchhofer A., 2006, « Wettrennen um Verlustabschlüsse. Zur Gemeinwirtschaftlichkeit der Schweizer Bahnen und ihrer Abgeltung », Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Geschichte 1, pp. 57-66.
    • Kirchhofer A., 2003, « Unentbehrliche Eisenbahn ». Die Finanznot der schweizerischen Privatbahnen 1918 – 1973 (lic. phil. hist. Universität Bern), Bern.
    • Knieps G., 1993, « Privatisierung und Deregulierung im öffentlichen Personennahverkehr », Zeitschrift für Verkehrswissenschaft 64/4, pp. 249-259.
    • Kommerzieller Dienst Personenverkehr der SBB, 1973, Übersicht über die gesetzlichen Grundlagen der Tarife, Bern.
    • Kunz R., 1955, « Die schweizerische Eisenbahngesetzgebung », in Eidgenössisches Amt für Verkehr (ed.), Ein Jahrhundert Schweizer Bahnen 1847 – 1947 (vol. 4), Frauenfeld, pp. 667-689.
    • Pfister C., 1995, Geschichte des Kantons Bern seit 1798. Im Strom der Modernisierung. Bevölkerung, Wirtschaft und Umwelt 1700 – 1914, Bern.
    • Merki C. M., 1995, « Die verschlungenen Wege der modernen Verkehrsgeschichte. Ein Gang durch die aktuelle Forschung », Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Geschichte 4, pp. 444-457.
    • Meyer H.R., 1976, « Verkehrwirtschaft und Verkehrspolitik ». Aktuelles und Grundsätzliches (Berner Beiträge zur Nationalökonomie), Bern.
    • Meyer H.R., 1966, « Falsche Verkehrspolitik durch Überschätzung der volkswirtschaftlichen Gestaltungskraft der Verkehrspreise », in : Schweizerisches Archiv für Verkehrswissenschaft und Verkehrspolitik 21, pp. 285-304.
    • Meyer H.R., Hess A., 1947, « Die staatliche Hilfeleistung », in Eidgenössisches Amt für Verkehr (ed.), Ein Jahrhundert Schweizer Bahnen 1847 – 1947 (vol. 1), Frauenfeld, pp. 430-432.
    • Mitchell B.R. (Ed.), 2003, International Historical Statistics : Europe 1750-2000, (vol. 2), New York, pp. 674-683.
    • Müller P., 1981, Die Finanzlage der Schweizerischen Bundesbahnen (SBB) im Vergleich mit der Deutschen Bundesbahn (DB), der Französischen Staatsbahn (SNCF) und der Niederländischen Staatsbahn (NS) zwischen 1955 und 1975. Möglichkeiten und Grenzen von international vergleichenden Finanzanalysen (Diss. rer. pol. Universität Bern), Bern.
    • Roth R., 1978, Die schweizerische Eisenbahnpolitik. Eine Ziel-Mittel-Analyse (Diss. rer. pol. Universität Bern), Zürich.
    • Ruchti E., 1973, « Problematische Abgeltung der Eisenbahnen », Schweizerisches Archiv für Verkehrswissenschaft und Verkehrspolitik 28/2, pp. 127-146.
    • Rüfenacht T., Salis Gross C., 1993, Der Eisenbahnbau und die räumliche Verteilung der Wirtschaft im Kanton Bern 1850 – 1910 (Liz. phil. hist. Universität Bern), Bern.
    • Saitzew M., 1932, Die volkswirtschaftlichen Aufgaben und die wirtschaftspolitische Behandlung der Eisenbahnen. Ein Beitrag zur Beurteilung des Wettbewerbes zwischen Eisenbahn und Automobil, Bern.
    • Sax E., 1878, Die Verkehrsmittel in Volks- und Staatswirthschaft. Die Eisenbahnen (vol. 2). Wien.
    • Spörri W., 1941, Die Lasten und Leistungen der schweizerischen Eisenbahnen für Staat, Volk und Wirtschaft (Schweizerische Beiträge zur Verkehrswissenschaft, Heft 4), Bern.
    • Skenderovic D., 1994, « Die Umweltschutzbewegung im Zeichen des Wertewandels », in : Altermatt U. (ed.), Rechte und linke Fundamentalopposition. Studien zur Schweizer Politik 1965 – 1990 (NFP 21 : Kulturelle Vielfalt und nationale Identität), Basel.
    • Stamm R., 1979, Ökonomische Betrachtungen zu den gemeinwirtschaftlichen Verpflichtungen der Schweizerischen Bundesbahnen (Diss. rer. pol. Universität Bern), Bern.
    • Treichler H.P. (ed.), 1996, Bahnsaga Schweiz. 150 Jahre Schweizer Bahnen, Zürich.
    • Voigt F., 1973, « Verkehr ». Die Theorie der Verkehrswirtschaft (vol. 1), Berlin.
    • Walter F., 1996, Bedrohliche und bedrohte Natur. Umweltgeschichte der Schweiz seit 1800, Zürich.
    • Weibel B., 1993, Privatisierung – Modewort oder Heilmittel ? (Podiumsgespräch anlässlich der Generalversammlung des Arbeitskreises Kapital und Wirtschaft vom 21. April 1993 in Zürich), Zürich.
    • Willeke R., 2001, « Verkehrsordnung im Wandel und noch ohne Konzept », Zeitschrift für Verkehrswissenschaft 72/4, pp. 223-234.
    • Willeke R., 1997, « Verkehrswissenschaft als Begleiter der Verkehrsentwicklung und Verkehrspolitik », Zeitschrift für Verkehrswissenschaft 68/1, pp. 52-72.
  • Swiss Federal Archives

    • Bundesblatt der Schweizerischen Eidgenossenschaft (BBl), 1848 – 1982, Bern.
    • Eidgenössisches Eisenbahn- und Postdepartement (EPED), 1951, Protokoll vom 22. Dezember 1951, p. 5 (Swiss Federal Archives : BAR 8100 (B), 1973/154, Bd. 92)
    • Kleiner Rat Kanton Graubünden, 1951, Schreiben vom 15. Dezember 1951, p. 4 (Swiss Federal Archives : BAR 8100 (B), 1973/154, Bd. 92).
    • Nationalrat, 1891 – 1982, Amtliches Stenographisches Bulletin der Bundesversammlung (Sten Bull SR), Bern.
    • Ständerat, 1891 – 1982, Amtliches Stenographisches Bulletin der Bundesversammlung (Sten Bull NR), Bern.
André Kirchhofer
André Kirchhofer est historien et docteur de l’Université de Bern, il a écrit une thèse de doctorat portant sur le service public des chemins de fer suisses entre 1850 et 1980. Il travaille à l’ASTAG, l’Association suisse des transports routiers, en tant que chef de la section politique et communication et donne des cours à l’institut d’histoire de l’université de Bern. Email : akirchhofer@bluewin.ch
Jonas Steinmann
Jonas Steinmann est historien et docteur de l’Université de Bern. Au cours de son doctorat, il a étudié l’économie des transports en Suisse au XXe siècle. Ses travaux de recherche se sont centrés sur le financement du transport ferroviaire. Jonas Steinmann a quitté le champ de la recherche et travaille actuellement à la Banque Cantonale de Bern. Email : jonas.steinmann@bekb.ch
Cette publication est la plus récente de l'auteur sur Cairn.info.
Cette publication est la plus récente de l'auteur sur Cairn.info.
Mis en ligne sur Cairn.info le 28/10/2008
https://doi.org/10.3917/flux.072.0039
Pour citer cet article
Distribution électronique Cairn.info pour Métropolis © Métropolis. Tous droits réservés pour tous pays. Il est interdit, sauf accord préalable et écrit de l’éditeur, de reproduire (notamment par photocopie) partiellement ou totalement le présent article, de le stocker dans une banque de données ou de le communiquer au public sous quelque forme et de quelque manière que ce soit.
keyboard_arrow_up
Chargement
Chargement en cours.
Veuillez patienter...